Although confusion is stemming from their administration and
interpretation, much research has been done to study educational production
relationships and to determine pupil performance. These studies are crucial
since they demonstrate the intricacy of empirical studies. Their findings also
have implications to topics such as salary determination, status achievement,
the school financing, and the impacts of education quality on urban location
and housing choice. They also have continually influenced judicial proceedings,
legislative debate, and executive branch policy deliberations. However, these
kinds of research have been difficult to follow because they cross disciplinary
boundaries.
I. Background
The Equality of
Educational Opportunity or the Coleman Report mandated by the Civil Rights
Act of 1964 remains to be the most influential study. It contains data on the
pupil attributes from 3,000 schools, as
well as their performance. It also focused on the significance of the
relationship between school inputs and pupil achievement and introduced a
collection of technical and cryptic concerns such as statistical significance,
analysis of covariance, production efficiency, multicollinearity, residual
variation, estimation bias, and simultaneous equations into the public policy
arena.
Input-output studies such as those found in the Coleman
Report have led to a fast growth in the number of analyses and a strong effort to
interpret the varying and contradictory outcomes. As more studies were
conducted, the estimated relationships were coined as "educational
production functions".
II. Textbook Analyses
The difference between a production function and other
descriptions of input and output relationships is the concept that it denotes
the maximum possible output for given inputs. The production function provides
a source of describing efficient production, the appropriate response of firms
to changes in technology or input costs. Its basic analytical concepts are
applicable to a wide variety of applications. They are, however, quite too
simple to use in practice; they require extensive modification for them to be
applicable to certain situations. The function is not generally known
theoretically and must be estimated, which raises further statistical and
conceptual concerns.
The greatest difference between production functions to
education and to other industries comes from the potential uses of the
analysis. While most firms will not alter their behaviour based on the results
of their production function, the findings and interpretations of the
educational production functions are discussed more extensively. Indeed,
Congress even holds hearings on the size of estimated coefficients; commissions
include results in supporting their policies; and courts receive testimony with
regards regression equations.
III. Conceptual Production Functions and Educational Realities
Studies for educational production functions comprise of
statistical analyses using observed pupil outputs. This information is obtained
from standardized test scores, attitudes, college continuation, and attendance
patterns. Variations are observed in terms of the actual measured inputs, the
level of aggregation of the variables, and the statistical methods employed.
Due to this, the studies generate different outcomes – some of them even
contradicting each other.
A. Measurement of Output
Most production function studies use standardized
achievement test scores, while others have used variables such as pupil
attitude, attendance rate, and dropout rates. On the other side, although most
production functions concentrates on varying quantities of a homogenous output,
this may not be suitable for education production functions as education
transforms inputs into pupils with varying attributes. Standardized tests lack
external validation, making discrimination and the division of the population
into different groups more likely.
Some studies attempt to deal with the influence of education
in the latter lives of citizens. For instance, economists have looked into the
impact of education to earnings and labor market performance. However, the
measure of how much education individuals attain is often insufficient.
Analysts frequently use schooling years to estimate education. The quality of
education, a more vital aspect, is seldom measured. Although some have tried to
include qualitative variables, these studies have been limited by data
availability and stringent assumptions with regards to school operations. The
findings become inconclusive and inadequate in giving guidance.
The relationship between schooling and labor market
performance is the chief concern of many policy studies. Many analysts have
also explored other areas like education’s part to job satisfaction, personal
health, the productivity of mothers occupied in household production, and the
impacts of the mother's education on the young children education. Furthermore,
scientists have also studied how education influences political socialization,
voting behavior, and even criminality.
In
spite of these developments, they have failed to address how the mentioned
outcomes are impacted by varying school programs and operations. The
examination of nonlabor market areas has the potential of providing a balanced
perspective on educational productivity. But so far, the existing studies yield
inconclusive results.
The notions of how education affects skill formation and
later experiences are still superficial. This is because cognitive skills may
not be the most significant outcome in distinguishing an individual’s success.
Although intuitively speaking, a more educated person will get a job done more
rapidly, less education may be better for tasks that require manual labor. The
hypothesis that educated individuals are more capable of performing complicated
tasks has important implications in studying the productivity and outputs of
schools. This can take place by considering the mechanisms by which school
interacts with the work place. This could offer insight on how to properly
assess the schooling outputs and how these consequences can impact the economy.
The school-earnings relationship becomes blurred because of
the fact that schools are capable of either yielding qualified individuals or
determining the competent ones. Economists and sociologists have paid more
attention to screening models as the social value of schooling may be
considerably less than the private value if it happens that schools are just
identifying the more able instead of actually sharpening their skills.
Moreover, the screening model proposes both potential reinterpretation of the
historical contribution of education to economic growth and revisions of
expectations about future returns to schooling.
The model also has direct implications for the measurement
of educational outputs and the analysis of educational production
relationships. Under it, the school outputs are information regarding the
relative pupil abilities. This indicates that more attention should be given to
the distribution of observed educational outcomes and their relationship to the
distribution of underlying abilities. In addition, the interpretation of some
studies may be significantly transformed since schools with a higher dropout
rate might actually be supplying greater information than those having lower
rates. However, no persuasive test has been made to differentiate between a
screening model and the standard production model.
Test scores seem to be an inappropriate measure for outcome since
empirical evidence is inconclusive about the relationship of test scores and
achievement. Despite of this, test scores are still being widely used because
they are easily available and since educators and parents still value them
important. Test scores also seem to efficiently pick individuals for further
schooling, which may relate to the real outputs of the selection mechanism.
If one intends to use test scores as an output measurement,
an appropriate scaling of scores must be considered, one that indicates how
different individuals are rather than one that merely ranks them. Also, there
is currently some movement to use criterion-reference tests. These tests relate
to some set of educational objectives. Although it is more intuitive to adopt
goals that relate to performance outside school, present studies are not
inclined toward the use of these objectives.
B. Multiple Outputs
Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regression is unsuitable to use
if there are more multiple outcomes that are simultaneously produced. In a
two-outcome assumption, where there are intermediate and a final outcomes and
an underlying production relationships are such that attitudes affect
investment and vice versa, the two structural equations can be estimated (but
not with OLS). It is possible, however, to estimate the reduced form of the
equation through OLS. This form explains both the direct and indirect impacts
of the explanatory variables. A number of single-equation analyses can be taken
as estimates for reduced-form relationships. Multiple-outcome methods are more
complicated.
It is feasible to construct models where joint production
appears important. However, there are circumstances where these issues are
insignificant. Without sufficient information about the range of outputs and
the potential decision rules, there is little that can be discussed.
Production
functions for total output are quite appealing as this is also what is done for
production function estimates for other sectors. Market prices are used to
gather outputs. Such prices, however, are not available for the education
sector. Besides, they are also inappropriate because the weights in the
decision function for outputs may be different from the market prices.
Production functions estimated with test-score measures might be more
appropriate in earlier grades, where more focus is given to reading and
arithmetic skills than in later grades. These outputs are more heavily weighted
than others at earlier grades, lessening the potential problems of multiple
outputs in later grades.
C. Inputs to the Production Process
Learning theorists in practice have little guidance to the
development of production functions; they do not participate with the
specification of inputs. Despite of this, these set of inputs verify the pedagogical
models.
The relatively fixed input of labor and capital could only
explain little. The fact that education studies attempt to provide much detail
about input differences makes it open to critique regarding the specification
of inputs. This is partly because input specification has not much attention in past analyses. There was
little conceptual clarity and the choice of input was deviation guided by
availability rather than conceptual desirability.
A somewhat acceptable model for pupil achievement comprises
of variables including family background, peer influences, school inputs, and
innate abilities. The chosen inputs are those considered relevant to the
individual pupil. The education production relationship is also cumulative in a
sense that past inputs still have effects on output although the value in
explaining output diminishes with more distant outputs. This, in turn, requires
the amount of data to be large. An alternative version of the model answers
this huge data requirement by taking only the value-added inputs. This,
however, lessens the data requirements at the expense of some assumptions.
Many educational inputs are not measured directly but are
substituted by other variables. This results to considerable measurement error
as effects of different inputs accumulate. The resulting deviation of the
empirical models to the conceptual models calls for some implicit assumptions.
One deviation from the conceptual models comes from the
measurement of inherent abilities. When this variable is not included, the
estimated impact of family background on achievement is biased upward but
biases in other parts of the model are smaller. If the “value-added” model is
used, the importance of the variables that are taken out will be even less as
the level effect will still be present and only the growth effect of the
omitted variable, innate abilities, will be taken out.
Another problem with the empirical evidences is the accuracy
of variable measurement. Only contemporaneous measures of explanatory variables
are usually available, which bloats the measurement error of cumulative
variables and makes the coefficients biased. The original model has more severe
measurement problems than the “value-added” model.
The
measurement concern is also more severe for school inputs. Data that are
usually provided only assess the schools or the teachers, but they are not
linked to the individual students. This dilemma is aggravated at later grade
levels where mean attributes may yield misleading indications of the actual inputs
to any given student.
In education production functions, there are two types of
concerns: the organizational and process attributes of the school and of the
individual teachers. The former can be accommodated in the conceptual
framework, but the latter creates serious problems. This is because educational
decisions that are made by the teachers are difficult to observe and measure.
They, however, cannot be ignored since variations in the teacher attributes are
vital.
Recognizing skill differences is important in discussing the
efficiency in production. In addition to that, it also modifies the
interpretation of teacher and school inputs. It is still rational to evaluate
the influence of the attributes of teachers because a lot of school decisions
are based upon these features. However, the estimated impact of these
attributes shows the ability either to predict or to develop more skilled
teachers.
More effort should be given to understand and measure both
the macro and micro organization and process school attributes. This will be a
potential breakthrough in production function analysis. Since there is no
assumption that schools systematically choose the best process for given
inputs, estimates of education technology should be conditional upon the chosen
macro organization and process characteristics. At the individual teacher
level, the impact of teacher characteristics can be thought of as reduced form coefficients.
D. Efficiency in Production
The efficiency of schools in production has important policy
implications since inefficiency opens the possibility of increasing school
outputs with no additional inputs. However, because estimation is based upon
the observed behavior of schools, the estimated relationships may not yield the
production frontier if schools are not producing the maximum output for given
inputs. The relationships will then portray average behavior, and this may not
be useful in predicting how changes in inputs affect outputs.
Two concepts are considered: economic and technical efficiency.
Economic efficiency refers to the correct choice of input mix given the prices
of inputs (and the production function). Technical efficiency refers to
operating on the production frontier.
Two arguments support the argument that schools are
technically inefficient. One asserts that educational decision-makers are not
guided by incentives to maximize profits or to minimize costs. The other one
argues that they might not understand the production process that’s why they
cannot be expected to be on the production frontier. The first argument does
not necessarily imply being off the production frontier, while the focus of the
second argument is related to the importance of macro organizational and
process choices.
The standard framework suggests that if two production
processes have the same input but have different outputs, inefficiencies are
present. But with skill differences, individuals with the same attributes make
productions decisions that are difficult to detect, measure, and model. Hence,
variations in outputs may not essentially reflect efficacy differences. This
point, however, does not eliminate the significance of the production
framework.
E. Miscellaneous Issues and Nonissues
Criticisms of estimated educational production functions
include the following:
1. Functional
form. There is little guidance about functional form. This issue seems to be a
second order problem because differentiating among varying functional forms is
impossible. Different functional forms may produce different results, which mean
that predictions based upon changes that are different from current
observations may be dangerous.
2. Level
of Aggregation. The conceptual model is at the individual student level, but
much analysis is conducted at a more aggregate level. The effects on the
estimates of aggregation are dependent upon the nature of educational
relationships. The most serious observed aggregation issue is one of errors of
measurement. With individual data about students but only aggregate data about
schools, aggregation becomes helpful because the errors in measurement for a
model of mean achievement and mean attributes are less than with individual
achievement and mean school qualities.
3. Selection
Effects and Causation. Although deemed important, information about causal
relationships between school factors and achievement cannot be directly estimated
from the observed data and correlations. They must be introduced from
information about the structure of the overall model. The most important issue
in the production function setting is the effects of teacher selection and
assignment mechanisms.
4. Multicollinearity.
In most observed production functions, multicollinearity has been observed.
This stems from the issue of not being able to unravel the separate effects of
highly intercorrelated exogenous variables. It often further yields to the
wrong sign of coefficients. This issue has been overrated. What is important is
to determine the right statistical method to use.
5. Statistical
Methods. The analysis of covariance is usually useless for answering the
questions under consideration. It just raises more questions without yielding
any added value.
IV. An Assessment of What We Know and What We Should Do
Empirical analyses of production functions often have
suffered 1) from concentrating upon a given attribute of schools or learning
process, or 2) from excluding other attributes that simultaneously affect
outcomes. These studies become a bit useless in modifying school policies.
Production function must produce some policy relevance by investigating the
effects of different factors on the performance of the schooling system.
It is observed that differences in family socioeconomic
background lead to significant achievement differences. Also, variations among
schools and teachers are detected to be important in achievement. On the other
hand, there is some indication that schools are economically inefficient as
they do not use the best mixes of inputs given their input prices and
effectiveness. Lastly, there are significant differences in production
functions by race and family background: the interaction of school resources
with the background characteristics of individuals is crucial.
There is much to be studied regarding the relationship
between school quality and performance. The earlier results on the operations
of the school system relate exclusively to test-score achievement, even though
validity of this measure is uncertain. This line of inquiry is important and
must be pursued. In addition, the influences of peer compositions as well as the
dynamics of the educational process are still vague. Moreover, severe data
problems call for the collection of new data for a variety of school
situations, which avoids the measurement issues and allows the observation of
longitudinal information. On top of these concerns, the following also needs
further attention: measures of alternative outputs, investigation of decision
processes with regard to alternative output mixes, identification and
measurement of process and organizational variables for schools and classrooms,
and expansion of models for more complicated realities such as high schools.
V. Concluding Remarks
Aside from influencing education policy-making, educational
production relationships also have connections to other research and policies like
the distribution of per student spending under alternative financing
mechanisms, the quality of governmental services, and the racial composition on
achievement. The importance of understanding the education sector has important
consequences for understanding other areas. Further research studies are yet to
be done as the current actions are quite superficial.
Source:
Eric
A. Hanushek, “Conceptual and Empirical Issues in the Estimation of Educational
Production Functions”, Journal of Human
Resources, Vol. 14, No. 3 (Summer, 1979), pp. 351-388.
0 comments:
Post a Comment