I. Introduction
It has been discussed that competition among schools for
students enhances school quality. In this paper the quality of public school is
measured by ultimate educational attainment, wages, and high school graduation
rates. The proof on competition’s effect on the quality relies on exogenous
variation in the costs of private school (serving as an alternative to public
school).
Two main ways public schools are affected by raising the
private school competitiveness:
1. Public
schools are obliged to boost school quality.
2. Increased
distribution of students among schools occurs (even though parents see private
school as a more competitive substitute for public school, it doesn’t imply
that private schools satisfy economic concepts of perfect competition). The
distribution depends on factors such as student’s ability/personality, and /or
parent’s preference regarding school setting and curriculum.
Simple comparison between public school student’s outcomes
in areas with and without considerable private school enrollment actually blurs
the effect of increased private school competitiveness with the rise in demand
for private schools in areas where there’s poor quality in public school.
Instrumental variables approach is used in obtaining
unbiased estimates of the effect of private school competition.[1]
Religious composition is considered to be a good exogenous measure of possible
competition for public schools because it is:
1. Correlated
with costs of private schools.
2. Uncorrelated
with other sources of demand of private schools, such as poor public school
quality.
II. A Simple Model for Public Schools, Private Schools and
Parents
The paper deals with the relationship among public schools,
private schools and parents, which determines the sorting of students amongst
schools and the quality of each school.
Two important extensions can be derived from using the
Tiebout-type model of local public goods provision.
Assume each town to be school district having its own fixed
housing stock and a local education market which is considered by the household
to be places of residence given its job condition. The local education market
has different attributes, urban or rural in nature, town boundaries, income and
educational spread, racial and religious composition. Households’ children have
known ability and personality. The utility of a household is a function of the
education produced in its children, its general interest in education and particularly
in private or religious education, its house quality, job location and school
location relative to the home and other services supplied by the residential
city.
Children’s abilities and personalities, household income,
and job location serve as restraints in maximizing the household utility when
they allocate themselves among school districts – under the condition there is
absence of private schools. Given fixed town boundaries, the level of public
school provisioning per town ought to be equilibrated through local property
tax and local public schooling value capitalization into house prices. However
by doing so would not generate an efficient equilibrium in which the public
schooling is offered at a minimum mean price and the household’s demand for it
is precisely satisfied. Inefficient equilibrium to a certain extent will lead
the demand for private schooling.
Private schooling occurs when it can provide for the
schooling demands of an adequate number of households who are willing cover the
costs on top of other taxes needed to pay for public schools. Though private
schools may have the same production function as of public schools, it may also
be different from each other, for example, due to greater degree of selecting
and disciplining pupils.
The first extension of the model is the theory on the extent
of variation of private school competition among areas. Schooling is most
frequently publicly offered for two reasons: (1) fixed costs are a large
portion of total costs and (2) people hope to distribute the cost of educating
their children over their lifetimes. Public school funded via property tax is
one way of managing such conditions. Private schools will be more competitive
alternatives since they need to find ways to reduce fixed costs and distribute
the expenses over people’s lifetime.
The second extension of the model is the theory on private
school competition’s influence on public school conduct. There are two possible
effects on public school administrators and teachers:
1. Given
difficulty in evaluating school personnel productivity, principal (residents) –
agent (school employee) problem tends to exist. However, the more private
schools are a competitive substitute to public school, the more information on
agents’ efficiency will be contained in the private schools’ enrollment share.
Greater competitiveness of private schools provides more information on school
productivity thus allowing residents’ response to potentially impose better
productivity.
2. Greater
competitiveness may also furnish higher financial incentives for school
personnel. Also, the number of public school pupils will also differ more with
residents’ satisfaction.
Evidently, private school competitiveness makes the total
school budget rely positively on public school productivity; however for per
student budget, the case is quite ambiguous as it may perversely increase when
the approval with public schools falls.
If total school and per-pupil budgets would depend
positively (negatively) on public school productivity or if school staffs
prioritize total school budgets (per pupil budgets) rather than per pupil,
greater private school competitiveness will enhance (weaken) the financial
incentives experienced by schools (respectively).
III. Implications of the Model
If public schools do improve productivity due to private
school competition it would by raising quality and not by reducing taxes. The
reduction of taxes would only lead to higher disposable income which can be
spent on private school tuition.
Furthermore, the model implies that greater private school
competitiveness will raise the degree of pupil sorting among schools. Greater
number of substitutes can only have a non-negative impact on the level to which
parents’ inclinations and pupils’ abilities determine the choice of school.
It is important to mention that the model do not suggest
anything with regards to the type of and the significance of sorting.
The model also suggests that given all else constant, lower
public school quality will lead more parents to demand for private schooling.
Also the homogeneity of the population will impact the
extent to which public schooling provision is effective as well as affect the
private school competitiveness. Hence,
there is a need to consider the probability of confusing the impacts of
population homogeneity on public schools with the effects of private school
competition.
IV. Empirical Strategy
First step is to determine the sign and magnitude of the
private school competitiveness impact on public schools; the next step would be
to distinguish between the mechanisms that can produce the observed sign and
size.
The representations of the model indicate that private
school enrollment share is likely endogenous to public school quality.
V. How Private School Costs Depend on Religious Composition
The empirical strategy of the paper relies on the fact that
the greater a denomination’s population density in an area; its schools are
better able to contend with public schools. This is because a substantial
portion of a denominational school’s revenues normally come from church
offerings which are from all denominational members not considering whether
their children attend the schools. Such system (which has an adequate aspect
wherein members greatly valuing the public goods will donate more) provides for
cost distribution over parents’ lifetimes. Another reason is that
denominational schools lessen fixed costs by sharing infrastructures,
equipment, and staff with churches and synagogues. Third reason would be the
parents’ preference wherein they would favor schools affiliated with their own
religious congregation. Lastly, an area heavily populated by a denomination’s
member can support schools at a shorter distance from each other so that
parents are more able to find a private school substitute located close by.
The four points can be examined with particular reference to
the Catholic Church, which is considerably the largest single religious
congregation in the U.S. The three types of Catholic schools are parochial run
by parish with 96% being elementary, diocesan which is under the control of a
bishop with 70% being elementary, and private owned by an order such as
Jesuits, with 85% being either secondary or a combination of elementary and
secondary.
The study indicates that households living in an area
densely populated by Catholics are more likely to live in a parish that is
geographically small, supports a school, holds a great number of Catholics and
has more people in religious orders eager to offer their services to Catholic
schools. Moreover, parents experience lower tuition, more accessible school
places, a shorter distance to the nearest Catholic school, lesser school
transportation troubles, and an area wherein other children also attend
Catholic school. However, between areas having comparable Catholic population
densities, there are still disparities in whether Catholic schools actually
exist.
In addition, there is evidence that a considerable share of
parents keenly compare public and private schools, and they do not send their
children to private denominational schools merely for religious motives,
majority of them are likely to cite academic standards and courses as the main
reason for not enrolling their children to public schools. However for some
religious parents, particularly conservative Christian parents, they
deliberately forgo academic quality for religious/moral values.
Another finding shows that various denominations have
opportunities to build critical masses which allow furnishing denominational
schooling simple and economical. However, only few denominations exhibit
interest in offering schooling.
Generally districts having denser Catholic population shares
that are more urban have bigger shares of households headed by females, and
more are Hispanic. However, counties with greater Lutheran population shares
are less urban and more homogenous with regards to race, income and family
composition.
Results indicate that the higher denomination’s population
shares in a district, the greater the chance that the religious congregation’s
schooling will be offered.
Catholic variables are expected to offer the best instrument
since the essential connections between population and school costs and
accessibility are observable. Catholic variables are also expected to have the
least correlation with unobservable variables that may be linked to school
quality.
VI. Data
The data required is on individuals’ schooling outputs,
their backgrounds, and (attended) school area’s attributes. The paper uses five
datasets which are merged geographically and focused on year 1980. Data on individuals are derived from the
National Longitudinal survey of Youth (NLSY) which is a panel of 12,686 men and
women aged 14 – 22, surveyed yearly since 1979. The backgrounds obtained from
NLSY are the respondent’s race, gender, number of siblings, parent’s
educational attainment, household’s denomination and frequency of religious
attendance. It is significant to control for the impact of the religion in
which the participant was raised and there is an importance in sorting out the
impact of living in a greatly Catholic area from the impact of living in a
Catholic household.
The second dataset is the Survey of Church and Church
Membership in the United States, 1980 which is 231,708 Judeo-Christians
parishioners in the U.S. The data provides each denomination’s devotees and
churches/synagogues for each of the 3,101 U.S. districts.
The third set is the 1980 National Center for Education
Statistics (NCES) Private Schools in America survey of 20,050 private schools
in the U.S. It includes denominational or other association, enrollment, grade
levels taught, tuition, subsidies and geographic location.
The fourth dataset is from the 1982 Census of Governments
which contains 16,270 public school districts in the U.S., consisting of 85,000
schools.
Lastly, the data was derived from the 1980 census and 1983
City and County Data Book which provide all the district attributes there than
religious composition.
About 2,097 observations are lost due to missing geographic
information, respondents didn’t attend public school, neither parent’s highest
level completed was reported and lacking information on district attributes.
VII. Results
The observation suggests that Catholic schools face higher
subsidies in areas more heavily populated by Catholics. Moreover a Catholic
school’s tuition seems to rely greatly on the extent of subsidy it experiences
– tuition decreases as subsidies increase.
Meanwhile, Catholic secondary school enrollment as a portion
of its district is decreasing in the mean tuition. Contributed teaching serves
as a good instrument for tuition since it lets a school provides lower tuition
while giving the same quantity of schooling and since the share of teachers who
supply their services is determined rather randomly by the control of the
school. The enrollment share is rising in the Catholic population share and the
Catholic Church density.
Although similar results can be said for the elementary
school enrollment, it seems as if private school competition at the secondary
level has greater impacts on public school pupils’ outputs than at an
elementary level. As have been repeatedly mentioned, Catholic area supports
schools that draw in more enrollment, and this appeal is partially brought
about by lower tuition and other factors.
Main results of the study indicate that Catholic school
enrollment shows both increased demand for private schooling given that public
school quality is low and positive impacts of private school competition on how
public schools function. In addition, a change in the Catholic population of a
district, such as an increase in the share of enrollment in Catholic schools
yields an extra percentage point increase in the mean years of education for
public school pupils.
With regards to frequency of religious attendance per
households, a percentage point increase of it in the share of the population is
linked to a below 1 year rise in public school pupils’ educational attainment.
Finally, Catholic secondary enrollment share increases teacher
salaries, decreases per-resident spending, and no considerable impact on
per-student spending.
VIII. What Explains These Results?
Holding the teacher wages and per-student spending are
likely to raise the positive impact of the Catholic school enrollment share on
student outputs. Exclusive of the indirect impacts on wage and spending, a
percentage point increase in the Catholic school enrollment share produces an
additional percentage point years of educational attainment, and some percent
higher salaries. Although the impact of teacher wage and per-student spending
on pupil outputs are too poorly estimated that it does not merit discussion, it
can be assumed that salary increases alone can explain the improvements in
schooling outputs.
In terms of sorting, given that the private school
competition has a positive impact on public school, consider the “sorting
story” wherein it assumes that increasing private school competition would
raise its enrollment of student who would otherwise perform below average in
the public schools. Hence, any factors that can reduce the cost of providing
private schooling enhance the pupil population remaining in the public schools.
The finding from testing this hypothesis shows that sorting or selection is
actually insignificant, and to accept such assumption would be to establish
acceptance that private school are extremely efficient. Further observation
however, shows that the sorting story implies that Catholic schooling, offering
considerably lower teacher salaries and using substantially less per student,
admits students who would perform below standard or be disorderly in the public
schools, and generate much better graduates than that of public schools. In
other words, if student sorting between public and private school is prohibited
to have an effect on the estimates, the private school enrollment share has a
similar effect on pupil outputs.
Lastly, increase private school competitiveness may
stimulate sorting that yields greater or smaller variation among pupils’
outputs; however the paper found no evidence for this probably due to the fact
that the sample size is not sufficiently large.
IX. Conclusion
The findings support the conclusion that increasing the
private school competitiveness to public schools has advantageous impact on
public schooling outcomes and on how public school operates.
(Note however that these results are only suggestive of the
impacts of policies that raise the public schools’ abilities to compete with
one another.)
Source:
Caroline
M. Hoxby, “Do Private Schools Provide Competition for Public Schools?”, NBER Working Paper 4978, (December 1994).
[1] Admission
into private schools is likely to be endogenous to public school quality, and
this endogeneity will result to downward-biased estimates of the competitive
effect of higher private school enrollment. (Carolyn Hoxby)
0 comments:
Post a Comment