I. Introduction
Vouchers, privatization, and decentralization are all being
used to improve local public goods such as education and crime prevention.
Nearly all studies focus on how these systems affect productivity. Interest in
this area stems from the observation that budgets for local public goods are
limited in developing countries and that cost increases are not complemented by
improved services in industrialized countries.
It is often assumed that local public good spending is
equally productive, regardless of how it is financed. Economic theory on local
public goods has long concentrated on how much should each person pay for and
receive. As such, a theory which balances productivity and allocative issues
should be developed.
The author built a model which illustrates how imperfect
information allows local public good providers to take rent. She also reveals
that information is usually organized in such a way that residents and local
public goods providers encounter agency problems. She arrived at a model
containing the following characteristics:
- Cost conditions vary across jurisdictions but are not fully observed
- Some cost conditions are determined by the characteristics of local residents
- Moving costs are usually high enough to discourage households from moving frequently across jurisdictions
- Some local public good qualities are observable even though they are unverifiable
Social
planners who wish to manage productivity would have to deal with costly
information gathering. Productivity depends on the information that is
collected. However, high productivity can also be attained using conventional
property tax finance as long as households have enough jurisdictions to choose
from. A Tiebout residential market modifies the information structure by making
demand information verifiable and by abolishing the need for information about
cost conditions. Local property tax finance manages productivity in a
decentralized way and does not depend on the political process of determining
property tax rates. Moreover, if someone were to design a process to manage
productivity, local property tax finance will meet the desired conditions.
II. Productivity in
the local public good literature
Tiebout’s
(1956) paper described local public good providers as cost-minimizing
entrepreneurs. The Tiebout process and its interaction with politics were
assumed to manage the allocation issues in local public goods. However, there
is no similar assumption for productivity. Also, the entrepreneurial model is
quite unrealistic for local public goods like public education because quality
is non-verifiable for such goods. Then again, the Tiebout process still offers
useful implications for producers and consumers.
Much
of the theoretical foundations of this paper are provided by the works of
Laffont and Tirole (1993) on optimal incentive mechanisms under imperfect
information as well as Epple and Zelenitz’s (1981) study on the crucial role of
politics even in the presence of a well-functioning Tiebout process. The latter
also considers incumbents to be vulnerable to rent extraction.
III. The foundations
of the model: household, jurisdiction, agents and costs
A. Households
Some households move so that
their moving costs are lower relative to their choice of jurisdiction. For all
others, their cost of choosing a jurisdiction is equal to their moving cost.
Households are also assumed to maximize their expected utility; their utility
depends on local public goods quality, services generated by property and other
consumption.
B. Jurisdictions (Public School Districts)
Jurisdictions
have fixed boundaries and there are different jurisdictions for each type of
household. The supply of potential jurisdictions is observed to be elastic.
They are classified as either commercial or agricultural.
C. Agents
There
are many agents who can offer to provide local public goods to a jurisdiction.
Such agents are assumed to be rent-maximizing. They can take rent through
reduced effort, improved job benefits, excess salary, and gifts. Because of
outside opportunities, an agent can quit if a jurisdiction offers him negative
or zero rent. This rent is quantified by subtracting an agent’s effort and cost
in producing the public good from the payment he receives for them.
D. Cost
Cost is a function of local public goods
quality, the agent’s effort, the type of household being served, and cost
conditions specific to a jurisdiction. Ceteris paribus, per-pupil costs
increase as quality increases, while it decreases as effort decreases. Cost
also varies according to the type of household because it is usually more
costly to provide education for households which cannot provide the
complementary inputs for schooling. It is not, however, a function of
jurisdiction size because it is assumed that there is no economies of scale.
IV. The information
environment
Information is verifiable if it can be observed with
certainty by planners or if the public can perceive it identically. For
households, it is assumed that they are able to identify their own type. In
addition, they can detect if households of the same type dwell in a particular
jurisdiction. Social planners however, have no capacity to determine such
information.
Households are capable of comparing the quality of
jurisdictions because they can observe and evaluate outcomes from local public
goods provision. This makes local public goods quality observable to households
within jurisdictions that serve their type. Quality, however, is not verifiable
because many outcomes are subjective and may be affected by household types. In
contrast, budgets allotted to agents are both observable and verifiable.
Households and jurisdictions also have no way to assess the quality of their
efforts.
Initially, an agent is unaware of the cost conditions of a
certain jurisdiction. But once he is commissioned to provide local public
goods, he learns its cost conditions so he could take them into account in
choosing quality.
Centralized rules for financing usually start from cost or
outcomes. Cost-based rules are poor at managing productivity because they do
not give agents the incentive to minimize cost for a given quality.
Outcome-based rules, on the other hand, are enacted occasionally and are
usually short-lived. For schools, outcome-based rules encourage agents to focus
on outcomes that are tested like student scores on state-wide tests; while
other outcomes are neglected. These rules can be improved by investing in more
information on objective outcomes, households, and the relationship between
them.
V. Local property
tax finance
Conventional local property tax finance give incentives to
produce services of high quality. For non-moving households, property tax rate
is chosen by means of a local political process. The outcomes of such
conventional political processes are determined by the preference of
incumbents. They choose the appropriate tax rate if they thought they were in a
jurisdiction with the worst cost conditions. Such choices must always be above
zero-rent rates of agents to prevent agents from quitting from producing the
needed services.
Each agent receives his revenue from local property tax.
Each set their marginal cost of producing higher quality equal to the marginal
revenue they earn by producing at such value. They also set the reduction in
costs from higher effort equal to the reduction in money utility from higher
effort.
Agents who have better cost conditions and those who offer
high quality often receive positive rent. This is limited, however, because
households keep some of the gains associated with unique cost conditions. In
additon, there are certain budget-quality combinations where no agents will
produce the required services because of insufficient compensation.
The housing market gives incentives for agents with good
cost conditions to produce higher quality. These agent rewards are not
necessarily drawn from tax rate changes. Most of the time, they are pulled from
incumbents so that they do not have to rely on political processes to reflect
their desires. Although incumbents want a complicated tax schedule to realize
capital gains from the appreciation of their properties, such tax rates might
cause agents to quit. For administrative simplicity, they stick to a particular
optimum tax rate.
VI. What a social
planner can achieve with a generous amount of information
Outcomes achieved by local property tax finance are similar
to those that are produced when a social planner has perfect information on
quality, household’s type, outcome, cost, and functional forms of rent and
utility functions.
Social planners have no capacity to prescribe the effort,
quality, and costs that agents should employ. As such, they instead offer
budget-quality, rent-minimizing packages, constrained by the fact that agents
will not compromise with zero-rents and that households can move anytime they
want. An incentive compatible option will be produced if it gives an agent
enough rent for offering high quality.
Social planners find the incentive-compatible option that
maximizes rent by determining how much an agent’s rent must increase as his
cost conditions fall. By doing so, an agent will have an incentive to report
his true cost conditions and make the effort appropriate for those cost
conditions. The social planner then minimizes rent relative to the incentive
compatibility constraint and the agents’ participation constraint.
VII. A comparison of
the local property tax solution and the social planner’s solution
Productivity differences between the local property tax
solution and the social planner’s solution are due to the assumption that the
social planer knows the form of agents’ rent functions. When the budget-quality
curve is below the rent-minimizing incentive-compatible curve, the financial
incentives for improving quality are not enough to cover the costs. Otherwise,
households will only be limiting, but not minimizing rent.
If we assume that households had enough information about
agents’ rent function, they will have a complex tax schedule. If not, they will
settle with a flat tax rate. Also, when social planners are not aware of the said
information, they will not be able to find the rent-minimizing
incentive-compatible curve. They will need to settle with the local property
tax solution – a solution which may not eliminate rent but can reduce it
significantly.
Outcomes under centralized finance are comparable with those
under local property tax finance in a residential market with many
jurisdictions. It can produce results that are similar to the product of social
planners who have all the necessary information. It is able to manage productivity
efficiently because 1) it makes information verifiable by providing a measure
of quality for cost – property prices; and 2) it partials out other necessary
details.
Local property tax-based finance is automatic and relatively
cheaper to use. It removes the disadvantages of moving costs and enables
households to use private information to identify households of their own type.
This allows household type to be cancelled out of the productivity problem. In
choosing and assessing schools, parents only need to make simple comparisons
using the people they know. They do not need to quantify their observations or
develop a complex analysis with it. This cannot be the case under centralized
finance.
In contrast, centralized finance does not automatically
employ information from individual households’ actions. Required information is
often unverifiable, costly, and difficult to use. It also allows producers to
extract rents by minimizing unverifiable quality or by exaggerating costs.
Source:
Caroline M. Hoxby, “The
Productivity of Schools and Other Local Public Goods Producers,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 74 (1999) pp. 1-30.
0 comments:
Post a Comment