I. Introduction
American higher education has been changed from a chain of
local autarchies to a nationally and regionally incorporated market wherein
every colleges experience many possible competitors for inputs and consumers.
The magnitude of the transformation is equivalent or even greater than that of
other domestic industries, such as banking and retail sales. The study explores
the significance of the changing market structures for tuition and students
subsidies (pricing), college quality, and pupils’ college decisions.
The paper provides both theory and empirical evidence that
explains how opening trade in the college markets yields a considerable
increase in average college tuition. If trade is open among various autarkies,
each having colleges that provide different quality of education, then theory
expects a number of responses. Colleges’ decline of market power on their local
consumers leads to a reduction in their rent and a subsequent rise in the mean
value they supply pupils. In addition, a loss in market power yields a rise in
the earnings of college inputs. Since inputs are comprised of students (who act
as consumers as well), high skilled pupils are expected to be given increased
subsidies after geographic market integration. Given an integrated market, the
mean college quality is expected to rise, and higher quality comes with an
increase in tuition with no decrease in value.
In the geographically integrated market, pupils acting as
both inputs and consumers are assigned more systematically among colleges on
the basis for their demand for education and ability to contribute to education
production. This translates to colleges having a student body that is growingly
homogenous and within-college heterogeneity drops. However, between-college
heterogeneity increases as colleges yield gradually more differentiated
products. The increasing distinction between colleges is reflected not only in
pupils’ college decisions but also in tuitions and subsidies, which are
expected to rise more variably.
The expectations come from three connected facts: (1) pupils
are both consumers and inputs; (2) they are to consume at the same college
where they serve as inputs; and (3) high demand pupils are usually high quality
inputs. High demand pupils are the same people whose gains benefit most from
colleges’ loss of market power – their demand is concurrently induced by the
loss of monopoly and market power.
II. Context
The study approaches a theory of the college education’s
industrial organization. The hypothesis is placed in the context of rising
college tuition, which is the most significant aspect of the college setting.
The increasing college fees in the United States have been a
constant problem for education scholars, legislators, and well-known analysts.
Several explanations were suggested as to why tuition seems to increase more
rapidly than inflation. For instance, according to Baumol (1967), since higher
education is an example of a non-traded service that gets rather few
productivity benefits from enhanced technology, then its price is expected to
rise quicker than that of the average goods. Rather, the price ought to
increase the earning of its primary inputs, such faculty and other professional
staff. Meanwhile, Ehrenberg and Murphy (1993) claim that the rise in tuition
prices overstates true increase in the college price, since the need-based
financial support automatically makes tuition increase quicker than tuition
revenue. The discussion of Clotfelter (1990, argued in Cook and Frank, 1993)
that tuition increase evince higher demand for college education due to a rise
in the measured rate of return to eduction, focuses on the notion that the
college education supply is inelastic. On the other side, Bennett Hypothesis, a
notable explanation for growing college tuitions, suggest that federal grants
and guaranteed student loans have driven the tuition hikes. The main idea of
the hypothesis is that federal government is a third-party contributor, hence
neither high education providers nor consumers have much motives to keep costs
down. The problem with this theory is that federal monies comprise a much
smaller portion of payments in college tuitions than in medical bills. As a
result, empirical evidence indicates that the impact of increases in the
federal Pell Grants on tuition is likely to be small.
The Clotfelter and Bennett hypotheses implicitly rely on the
presence of major market imperfections in the supply of college education, for
instance barriers to entry, inefficient consumer information and so on. Market
imperfection is even given more weight in the rationalizing the continuing
increase of tuition, which can be roughly identified as collusive behavior
among colleges.
The changing market structure of college education doesn’t
seem to compete with theories regarding the changing demand/supply condition
for education. For example, considering the college education’s industrial organization
is complementary to the Baumol and Ehrenberg/Murphy theories. The study shows
the remarkable increase in private college tuition in relation to the consumer
price index between 1940 and 1993, particularly from 1955 to 1965 and from 1985
to present. Focusing on the tuition revenue per pupil rather than just the
tuition, it can be observed that the tuition revenue did increase more
gradually than tuition. Although this
confirms the Ehrenberg/Murphy hypothesis, a considerable increase in tuition revenue
per pupil is yet to be explained. Meanwhile, if faculty wages are used instead
of CPI, the results show a faintly lower rate of rise in general. Although this
supports the Baumol hypothesis, the theory itself does not provide explanation
for the recent tuition hikes.
On the contrary, there appears to have a partial conflict
between the hypothesis proposed in this study and the Clotfelter and Bennett
hypothesis. Even though their reasons for the increased demand are entirely
compatible with a progressively competitive market for college education, their
mechanisms through which higher demand leads tuition to rise are in conflict
with the increasingly competitive market.
Overall, tuition increases with demand, but market power
explanations imply that colleges use the higher demand to raise their rents.
If, alternatively, colleges’ market power is declining then tuition is
increasing owing to the fact that open market has fueled quality competition.
Higher demand merely strengthens the effect of market forces.
Meanwhile, there is direct conflict between the hypothesis
proposed in this study and conniving theories of college behavior. The American
higher education’s changing market structure proposes that collusion should
have significantly become harder and more prevalent during the post war period;
however, antitrust case might have been due to increasingly competitive market
structure.
III. The Changing Market Structure of American Higher Education
A. Evidence on the Geographic Integration of the College Market
From 1940, college pupils have given colleges’ geographic
proximity to their homes reducing weight in their college options. Thus each
college has experienced a broad market of potential pupils. The results
demonstrate that the share of pupils who enrolled to colleges “in-state”
dropped from 1949 to 1994. The decline was more noticeable among private
colleges.
The results also showed that colleges increasingly drew from
the entire nation or a huge region. However a better measure of the
capaciousness of a college’s market is a Herfindahl index of the concentration
of its pupils’ residences. The index is equivalent to one if a college’s entire
enrollment is from in-state, and moves closer to zero as a college’s enrollment
is spread among the potential states-of-residence. From 1994, the mean private
and public college’s Herfindahl indexes dropped considerably.
The statistics derived by the study showed a rising share of
pupils going to four-year colleges applied to at least one college that was not
merely outside their home state but also beyond the states that connect it.
The four determinants of college choice considered by the
study: (1) the college’s estimated distance from the student’s home, (2) an
indicator for the college being in the pupil’s state of residence, (3) the
college’s tuition, and (4) the absolute disparity between the colleges’ mean
joint SAT score and the pupil’s joint SAT score, are found to be statistically
significant, however the geographic variables importance declines over time. A college’s imposing high tuition, all else
constant, eventually becomes a more crucial hindrance to students.
B. Evidence on the Causes of Increased Geographic Market
Integration
The most significant likely causes of geographic market
integration for higher education are: the advent of modern standardized
admission testing in 1943–1948; the information exchange system among pupils,
colleges, and scholarship benefactors that was primarily produced by the
National Merit Scholarship Program in 1956–1958; the introduction of
standardized financial need analysis; tuition reciprocity arrangements among
states’ public college systems; deregulation in the airline and
telecommunication industries led to considerably lower fees for long-distance
travel and communication; and low mobility expenses for pupils who went to
college on the GI Bill.
The other causes of integration rely on variation in pupils’
and colleges’ degree of information on one another.
Despite the fact that college fixed effects conspicuously absorb
much of the variation in the market; the measured reasons were found to be
statistically important determinants of the measures of market structure. Colleges deal with more competitive markets
when their long-distance costs drop, when their state has a tuition reciprocity
arrangement (only have an effect on public school), when admission testing is
implemented in their states, and when there is more corporate aid for the
National Merit Program in their area.
IV. Theory
A theory of the industrialization organization of the market
for college education and the impacts of having an open trade in such market is
drawn.
A. Geographic Integration of Imperfectly Competitive Markets
The study explains the implications of the geographic
integration of the market for college education through a simple situation: the
geographic integration of autarkies, with each having a college education
monopoly producer.
Given such condition, geographic integration has
pro-competitive impacts since the earlier monopolists fight with each other for
consumers and for inputs. This lowers price-cost margins and does well for the
consumers and increases salaries of college staff, respectively. Such
occurrence will be referred to as the “loss of monopoly power’ and “loss of
market power”. These incidents come across the case of college education of
varying quality, or vertical differentiated college education. Vertical
differentiation is important since it is realistic and it yields the market
power that is assumed for the autarkic colleges. As a result, it validates the
assumption that the colleges in the autarkies had market power.
B. Geographic Integration of Markets with a Vertically
Differentiated Product
Take into account a local autarky wherein there are a few
colleges producing education of different quality. Production of college
education has several significant attributes. Colleges have high fixed expenses
of furnishing education with respect to their variable costs. Variable costs
are roughly flat for a substantial region, up to the position where the college
must do a major extension in their physical plant or faculty. Generally, the
ratio of the high quality colleges’ to low quality colleges’ fixed costs is
greater than the ratio of their variable costs. Likewise, the ratio of pupils’
eagerness to pay for a high quality college to a pupils’ eagerness to pay for a
low quality college exceeds the ratio of high and low quality colleges’
variable expenses.
If pupils have heterogeneous demands for college quality,
the output is a market in which colleges generate educational services at a
variety of quality levels. The finite number of quality levels provided is
contingent on the distribution of pupil demands, but does not rely on the
market scale. Several colleges do not
have direct competitors at the level of quality they belong to. Price
competition is slackened by the vertical differentiation of colleges – this is
a natural oligopoly.
Going back to market power of colleges in the autarkies,
this time not from assumption but a natural aspects, provided that autarkies
have initial distribution of pupil demands
that overlap, the output of geographic integration will be more
straightforward competition among colleges. Such integration will place more
colleges in the propinquity of each quality level provided. This will reduce
the efficiency of vertical differentiation for relaxing competition, and
colleges will suffer the loss of monopoly and market power.
Furthermore, geographic integration has an added impact in
the case of natural oligopolies with vertical integration. As autarkies join
together, the mean college quality rises since they experience greater marginal
returns to expenses on quality enhancements. Thus for a given increase in
quality, a college can draw in more pupils. There is also a mean price hike
that corresponds to the mean quality developments, but the price hike is
coextensive and not welfare-reducing.
C. The Industrial Organization of the Market when Students are
Inputs as well as Consumers
The college’s quality is partially identified by the peers
of a potential student. Hence, pupils are both inputs and consumers in the
production of college education. In addition, they should be inputs at the same
college where they act as consumers. Lastly, pupils having high demand for
quality education are potential high quality inputs.
According to Rothschild and Stiglitz (1995), since pupil
double-hat as consumers and inputs, net tuition (tuition minus any grants)
merges the price that a pupil pays and the salary he is given. In a simpler view, colleges might impose
tuition on pupils whose input quality was negligible and provide scholarship to
other pupils. The student’s wage may be regarded as the entire subsidy he is
given: his education costs subtracted by tuition and institutional grants.
Every pupil at a college is a possible recipient of subsidy typically through
tuition that does not cover educational cost.
An immediate impact after integration is the increase of
quality demanded by high quality (and high demand) pupils. This is owing to the
fact that they are the primary receivers of the loss of market power – the
increase in “wage” meant being able to afford more college quality.
If colleges provide vertically differentiated services and
offer similar “wage” for a certain input quality, then high demand/high input
quality pupils will go to high quality colleges. Consequently, their presence
will improve the colleges’ quality. Such is the McPherson-Whinston multiplier
effect.
Regarding how the multiplier effect turns price competition
rather unsuccessful, assuming that a college competes by reducing the tuition
it imposes for its service quality level, then the college draws in new pupils,
but a disproportionate number of those students have low demand and low
quality. The college’s quality declines due to peer effects, and equilibrium is
restored with the college at a lower fee and lower quality.
Now considering a college that competes in quality through
offering high “wages” or merit scholarships to draw in pupils it could not
attract, otherwise. Although a college may improve its quality, it is
implausible to achieve moving up in levels of quality via this mean, since a
college need to outlay more for every high input quality pupil than a college
that provides high quality educational services. In equilibrium, the college
that started with high fixed costs and high service quality has the possibility
of maintaining its position and its high quality pupils.
In a nutshell, the theory expects at least eight responses
to geographic market integration:
1. A
college’s loss of monopoly power, yields increased value for pupils as
consumers;
2. A college’s loss of market power, yields
greater subsidies for pupils being high quality inputs;
3. A
boost in the mean college quality due to investments in quality earn greater
returns;
4. A
rise in the mean college tuition is proportionate to the increase in average
quality;
5. Augmented
allocation of pupils among colleges in accordance to their demand for quality;
6. A
greater increase in quality as well as tuition, for colleges that were
initially of high quality, because high demand pupils have their demand
heightened by the income impact of the loss of market power;
7. Odd
sustainability of quality competition in comparison to price completion because
of the multiplier effect favoring the former;
8. Raising
variety among colleges in terms of student ability, quality, tuition, and
subsidies.
D. A Note on Colleges’ Other “Consumers”
Some colleges provide a subsidy to each of their pupils and
such grants are possible since colleges have “consumers” other than their
existing pupils. For private colleges, the “other consumers” encompass of
sponsors of research, such as foundations and donors, such as former pupils.
For public schools, aside from sponsors and donors, the primary “other
consumer” is usually the state government.
For the purpose of this study, it is sufficient to
acknowledge that the actions of other consumers is similar to the conduct of
high demand pupils (as consumers) and the data may overstate the subsidies
furnished to high quality pupils. Similar colleges that supply high subsidies
to high ability pupils will be providing
high pay to other inputs that are being acquired by the colleges’ “other
consumers”.
E. The Differing Effects of Geographic Market Integration on
Private and Public Colleges
Public colleges in the United States are considerably more
restrained than private colleges in their admission and tuition policies,
college scale, use of funds, and ability to price discriminate among students.
Due to the constraints, public colleges are incapable to compete in the upper
region of quality level. On the other hand, they are also shielded from the
revenue losses related to losing high demand, high quality pupils that some colleges
can suffer from.
Selective public colleges in autarky experience a difficulty
to shift to geographically integrated markets since many of their pupils are
high demand consumers likely to be attracted to colleges that are less
restricted on increasing quality, admissions selectivity, and tuition as a
reaction to market integration.
F. A Note on Horizontal Differentiation
Another possible response of colleges to geographic
integration may be through horizontal differentiation, which relaxes direct
price and quality competition of colleges having relatively similar service
quality. For instance, a college finding a comparative advantage may offer
programs to a particular market niche.
V. Data
Since the market structure and price theory mentioned so far
are relevant to baccalaureate education in the United States, therefore each
college included in the analysis has been constantly baccalaureate-granting
from 1940 to present.
A panel of 1,221 colleges, with 731 private and 390 public,
covering the period from 1940 to 1991 was used. Every American
baccalaureate-granting college in the study had constant data on tuition,
tuition revenue, college expenses, and students’ residence from 1940 to
present, and also data on admission test scores from 1960 onwards.
For the period from 1966 and beyond, the primary sources of
enrollment and financial data on the college where Higher Education General
Information Survey (HEGIS), the Integrated Postsecondary Education Data Systems
(IPEDS), and CASPAR, which is a panel version of selected variables from HEGIS
and IPEDS.
Sources of data on admission tests scores of colleges’
enrolled pupils are from Cass and Birbaums’ Comparative Guide to American
Colleges, Peterson’s Guide to Undergraduate Study/ Peterson’s Guide to Four Year
Colleges, and Barron’s Profiles of American Colleges. Lastly, some unpublished
data was supplied by The College Board.
Meanwhile information on the college students’
state-of-residence is derived from a set of “Residence and Migration” surveys
carried out by the Department of Education.
The main source of the test score, the pre-1972 residence,
and pre-1966 financial data was the American Council on Education’s (ACE)
American College and Universities, an array that encompasses every
ACE-accredited college. Minor sources such as Lovejoy’s College Guide/Complete
Guide to American Colleges and Universities and others were able to help
complete the data.
All National Merit data were derived from the National Merit
Scholarship Corporation’s annual reports. Census of Population and Housing
supplied the data on the median income and share of adults having 16 years of
schooling.
VI. Evidence
It is important to mention that since there is no measure
that fully explains the market structure in higher education, the regressions
are expected to underestimate the true impact of market structure on tuition
and other dependent variables. The statistics and regressions are all weighted
by enrollment in order to accurately (as possible) give a national
representation of the market for baccalaureate education.
A. The Effect of Geographic Integration on the Distribution of
Students Among Colleges
Theory predicts that geographic integration of the American
market for college education should raise the between-college variance and
reduce the within-college variance in pupils’ admission test scores. This
implies that consumers will gather more homogenously anchored on their demand
for quality. In addition, since students act as both inputs and consumers, they
would tend to increase the vertical differentiation among colleges given the
process above.
The findings on the distribution of combined SAT scores
between colleges illustrate a decline in the average SAT scores and the
variance have increased quickly. Much of the rise in between-college variance
in average test scores was observed among private schools.
The results demonstrate private colleges obtained
between-college variance by extending out the tails of the distribution, in
contrast to public colleges which expanded the distribution of test scores in
the middle of the distribution. This is because public schools experience
constraints on their admissions policies brought about by state legislatures.
As a consequence, they are not seen extreme points on the admission test scores
distribution. Constrained public colleges that are initially selective can face
trouble in keeping their mean admissions test scores, while unconstrained
private colleges may admit some of their best potential pupils.
The Herfindahl indices derived by the study show that the
concentration of National Merit Scholar has not been so high, but has grown
over time – from a Herfindahl index equivalent to equally distributing scholars
to more than a hundred colleges in 1956 to a Herfindahl index translating to
the allocation of Scholars equally among less than fifty colleges in 1991.
The statistics obtained also presented a break in the trend
towards more concentration between 1966 and 1971; the break was due to a
deliberate alteration in the method of scholarship allocation. The change was
intended to distribute the scholarship more equally among students’
state-of-residence – thus a reducing the concentration of scholars.
Meanwhile, the results show that the within-college variance
in students’ admission test scores substantially decreased from 1966 to 1991.
Further analysis has the market structure measured by two
alternative measure of concentration (not competition): the share of pupils
from “in-state” and the Herfindahl index of the concentration of students’
state of residence. Note that the rise
in geographic integration of the college market and in competition is expressed
through a decline in the measures of concentration.
It seems that given a market with greater geographic
integration and (thus) more competitors, the colleges’ mean SAT scores have the
tendency to rise, and particularly more so if it was initially a high
selectivity college. An effect of greater competition is it increases the
average college test scores. Another is the increasing effect it has on the
difference between the test scores of pupils who attend the highest quality
schools to those who attend the lowest quality schools.
In addition, the expected impacts of geographic integration
on the average test score and between-college spread in test scores are larger
for private than for public colleges. Public colleges struggle to keep their
average SAT scores when they’re experiencing growing competitive market
structures. At first, comparatively elite public colleges admit pupils who have
the most potential to go to private colleges or other public colleges when the
market turns competitive.
On the other side, growing geographic integration in a
market causes the participating colleges’ student body to become less
heterogeneous.
All the preceding results confirm that heightened geographic
integration and competition in the market are likely to improve the average
college’s student quality, raise the student ability between-colleges, and
decline the student ability within-colleges. The results suggest that the
college quality has become more variable since 1940. It is possible that the
value of educational services provided has become more variable over the period
since colleges compete for high quality students.
B. The Effect of Geographic Integration on College Tuition
Since 1940, the tuition was observed to have increased
rapidly, with the public colleges’ in-state tuition consistently, considerably
lower than that of private colleges’. Meanwhile the public colleges’ tuition
distribution remained significantly narrower than that of private colleges’
tuition, especially during 1971 to 1991.
Even though college quality has grown on the average, the
vertical differentiation has been observed more significantly in private,
rather than in public higher education. However it has yet to be proven if the
college market integration has been a substantial determinant of the general
increase in tuition and the broadening of private colleges’ tuition
distribution.
The output indicates that private colleges in an
increasingly integrated and competitive market impose higher tuitions. Deeper
analysis finds the changing market structure to be accountable to a
considerable share of increases in private colleges’ average tuition and in the
variance of private colleges’ tuition.
In contrast, the impact of market integration in tuition for
public colleges is more modest. Growing market integration induces public
colleges (particularly the highly selective) to hike their tuition on average
as well as to shrink the tuition distribution (through low selectivity public
colleges increasing their tuition almost as fast as high selectivity colleges).
The reason for this is the fact that public colleges that are initially low
selective are the same colleges that conventionally maintained very low
in-state tuitions. Such methods turn out to be unmanageable (since residency
requisites for in-state tuition are hard to monitor and pupils try to trade the
subsidy in a highly integrated college market) and unfamiliar (since
middle-class taxpayers’ children, conventionally the main beneficiaries of
public colleges, are unwilling to be limited to choosing only amongst in-state
public colleges) as college markets integrate and pupils grow to be more
mobile. Such students do not want
geographic location to be the only determining factor of their college choice,
consequently, given the expectation that these students are unlikely to use up
the benefits of a highly subsidized public college system, the taxpayers opt
not to support high subsidies but rather agree on increasing tuition.
The growingly competitive market structure of American
higher education seems to account for the large share of the rise in college
tuition, particularly among private colleges, the expansion of the private
college tuition distribution, and the shrinking in the public college tuition
distribution.
C. The Effect of Geographic Integration on Subsidies to
Students
First off, per-pupil subsidy which unlike per-student
scholarship is insensitive to a college’s financial support policy is merely
the differences between college expenditure per student and tuition revenue per
student.
The theory expects that if market integration raises average
college quality as well as college tuition, then the colleges offering the
biggest subsidies will be the same colleges that would experience those
increases since they draw pupils whose “wage” is high.
One of the observations is that the median public subsidy is
consistently greater (and increased faintly faster) than the median private
subsidy. Although it is erroneous to associate the entire rise in subsidy with
pupils, it is evident that some pupils go to colleges wherein their tuition
payments cover just a part of their education costs.
Another observation is that market integration induces
subsidies to grow by a tiny amount in the typical private college, and by a
substantial amount in colleges that are initially highly selective, while no
rise in subsidies for the case of private colleges that initially had low
selectivity.
A notable outcome is that the colleges that increase their
student quality and tuition the highest owing to a more competitive market are
also the same colleges that increase their subsidies the most. However this
particular fact is in conflict with several collusive theories of tuition
hikes. Majority of the collusive theories suggest that colleges that can impose
higher tuitions must gather higher rents and do not offer greater subsidies.
Meanwhile, a decline in market concentration yields
statistically insignificant effect in the per-student subsidy for the common
public college and low selectivity public colleges. These results imply that market integration
has a certain strong competitive impact on initially selective public colleges,
pressuring them to contend against private colleges and other public colleges
for their mobile, high quality, potential pupils.
VII. Conclusion
The increasing competitive market structure brought about by
geographic integration of previously remote markets, has led American colleges
to increase their quality, their tuitions, and their costs. It also induced
colleges to be more varied, in order for the distribution of quality, tuition,
expenditure, and student quality among colleges to be considerably broadened.
On the contrary, the student ability distribution within any individual college
has shrunk. The changing market
structure was found to account for roughly 50 percent of the tuition increase
of typically selective private colleges since 1950, as well as for the smaller
tuition hikes for public colleges and less selective private colleges.
On the other hand, the changes in tuition equivalent to
commensurate changes in college quality are implied by the theoretical and
empirical evidence. The empirical results suggest that the average student has
higher utility in the face of geographically integrated market regardless
paying higher tuition.
The growingly competitive market may likely explain the
colleges’ increasing horizontal differentiation – moving away from generic
curricula and towards “market niches”, to which they serve the students’
particular needs. However, evidence for horizontal differentiation is simply
subjective.
The changes in the market structure are partially the result
of the fundamental and irreversible changes in pupils’ costs of geographic
mobility and the amount of information that pupils and colleges have regarding
one another. The progressively strong market forces in college education limit
the growing share of colleges’ choices. It is worth mentioning that much of the
former literatures on college behavior regard colleges as independent decision
makers and not as organizations whose decisions are progressively determined by
factors outside their control. Thus, policy makers must acknowledge that
arbitrary restraints on some colleges’ prices or expenses can potentially
induce reactions from pupils as inputs and consumers.
Source:
Caroline M. Hoxby, “How the
Changing Market Structure of US Higher Education Explains College Tuition” NBER Working Paper 6323. (December
1997).
0 comments:
Post a Comment