Does Competition among Public Schools Benefit Students and Taxpayers?

Various suggested reforms for elementary and secondary schooling in the United States are driven by increased parental choice. These reforms include intra-district and inter-district choice, vouchers for private and charter schools. Supporters of such reforms expect that competition would improve schools while those against it worry that the students’ method of choosing among schools may harm the educational views of some students. The reforms broaden the traditional method of school choice in the United States, which is a process regarded to be a main example of the Tiebout process, by which residential choices identify the spending on, and quality of local public goods.
The aims of this paper are to explain the existing system and to show the general attributes of school choice that contributes in coming up with reforms.
There are likely trade-offs given any forms of school choice. On one hand, it may offer students the chance to self-distribute in such a way that it may assist in learning or it may hinder the education of at least some peers. On the other, choice may strengthen the competitive mechanism that reinforces schools having high pupil achievement per spending or high productivity.
In addition, since there is a need to know whether the Tiebout choice impact relies on its financial implications or just on parents being more able to match their children with schools, this paper deals with some questions:
1. Is there less possibility that parents enroll their children in private schools provided they have more choice among public schools?
2. Do states' school finance programs that reduce the Tiebout process’ financial significance decreases the choice impact?

I. The Importance of Analyzing Tiebout Choice

The analysis of Tiebout choice allows understanding of the general-equilibrium impact of choice among schools. It would take years before any reform could have the permeating impact, as any short-term effect of reforms are misleading since they rely unduly on the pupil actively making a choice in the years right after a reform. Till numerous children have an augmented degree of choice, it is improbable for reforms to have an impact on public schools much, either through competitive pressure or through distribution.
Furthermore, understanding the Tiebout process is crucial since reforms are layered on top of the existing system. The majority of reforms would extend, not initiate, choice. Ignoring Tiebout choice is like disregarding the fact that some of the expected effects of reforms are have already been attained by Tiebout choice.
Finally, study of Tiebout choice is also for practical reasons. There is difficulty in determining the choice impact, as opposed to the causes and correlates of choice programs, except for the case of Tiebout choice. Recognizing the problem is more manageable since the Tiebout choice in an area mainly relies on historical conditions that are arbitrary with regards to modern schooling.


II. What Theory Predicts About Tiebout Choice?

Tiebout choice can have an effect on private allotment efficiency, social allotment efficiency, and schools' productivity. It is observed that Tiebout choice tends to increase private allotment efficiency, even when combined with political mechanism, such as voting on local property tax rates. With more school districts, it is easier for households to distribute themselves into groups that are relatively uniform with respect to their preferences on schooling and property. Hence, equilibrium is wherein households are likely to have access to schools near to what they privately prefer. The impact of free-rider problems, which distorts the Tiebout equilibrium, is lessened given that there are more school districts.
One of the implications of the private allotment efficiency result is that to a point, greater sorting decreases the magnitude to which households pay for school programs they do not value, Tiebout choice increases the value of school quality that households want to buy. In addition, given greater private allotment efficiency in public schools, household will have lesser tendencies to enroll their children to private schools. Also, better Tiebout choice means more sorting in terms of taste for or ability to benefit from education. For instance, a school district may come up with a group of households having the same desire for progressive curricula, hence to a certain degree, greater sorting enhances match quality between pupils' needs and schools' offerings, and thus Tiebout choice will increase the mean pupil performance.
Meanwhile the increase in private allotment efficiency brought about by Tiebout choice does not automatically lead to a rise in social allotment efficiency given there are human capital spillovers among students or neighbors. If thrusting more knowledgeable students into an encounter with less knowledgeable students would raise social welfare, an equilibrium in which more educated pupils are self-sorted may be socially ineffective. Unfortunately, the true impact of the contact between over-achieving and under-achieving pupils is unknown. Thus, it is uncertain whether social allotment efficiency always, sometimes or never increases as private allotment efficiency augments.
In general, the theory expects that Tiebout choice enhances school productivity. Provided that households have difficulty identifying producers' effort, validating the quality of schooling inputs and verifying schooling outputs, then schooling producers can earn rent. Such agent-principal concern is relieved by Tiebout choice since school budgets grounded on property taxes form a method that naturally integrates various households' private observations of schooling output and schooling inputs. These observations regarding schools establish property prices in all school districts, and schooling producers charging excessive rent are reprimanded through cutbacks in their school funds
Lastly, there is also uncertainty as to whether Tiebout choice increases or decreases total expenses on schools. Although it is expected for households to purchase greater achievement, it however cannot be predicted as to whether they will pay more in total, provided the fall in price.

III. An Empirical Version of the Theoretical Predictions

Theory implies that Tiebout choice directly influences the segregating and the incentives for productivity of schools and indirectly impacts productivity, achievement, school expenditure, and private schooling.
As of now it is assumed that choice is measured accurately and that all variation in choice is exogenous. The first prediction has the ratio of the reward provided by the market to administrators who develop productivity to how much Tiebout choice is present in the particular educational market to be greater than zero. Such prediction can be only indirectly examined through looking at the connection between choice and productivity and attempting to remove the impact of sorting.
The second prediction is that choice stimulates self-segregating, thus each school district has households that are more uniform in terms of their preferences for a schooling type and school expenses.  Theory deals with the joint impacts of household features (such as income) on education preferences that become more homogeneous. Given more choices in an educational market, the homogeneity of household attributes in its districts will vary and some properties are likely to become more homogeneous in every district. This prediction implies that Tiebout choice has an effect with an unknown direction to the heterogeneity of a particular attribute in each school district, in relation to the heterogeneity that would exist if an educational market is only one district.

IV. The Identification Problem

The two identification problems that can potentially affect the analysis of Tiebout choice are:
1. Threat of omitted variables bias.
The magnitude of choice in an educational market is due to several factors that affect the supply of school districts and the demand of the population for school districts. In assessing the choice impact, there is a need to depend only on the disparity in choice that comes from the supply side. Note that the level of the bias declines as other factors are included, but it is impossible to determine when all bias had been removed, also the sign of such omitted variables bias cannot be predicted.
2. Threat that the observed choice to be endogenous.
The degree of choice noticed in a market can also be, partially, a reaction to schools' observed productivity. This strict endogeneity can negatively bias estimates of the effect of choice on productivity.
The best solution to the identification problem is a set of valid tools that is, a set of variables that impact the supply of jurisdictions but are uncorrelated with factors that impact the demand for jurisdictions.

V. Measuring the Degree of Tiebout-Style Choice

The key to assessing the degree of Tiebout choice is to consider how households make residential decisions. First, account for the boundaries of the educational market over which households exercise choice. Second, consider the expenses related with implementing the choice. For instance if households' endowments are regarded to be a given, then each household experiences two main limitations on its residential choice: income and job location. Hence the educational market on which it practices Tiebout choice includes all school districts in a viable commuting distance from/to its job(s). Such markets are inclined to correspond to Census-characterized metropolitan areas of the United States. The empirical work is limited to the analysis of metropolitan schools and pupils.
Third, take to account the implementation cost of Tiebout choice in a metropolitan area. The crucial expenses include the costs of selecting a residence for its associated schools rather than for its other attributes. The household can pick various degree of school spending only by selecting among different school districts. In general cost is naturally a function of the number, extent, geographic setting, and housing stock of school districts within the metropolitan area. If households have the ability to select among different school districts offering equivalent residences, where comparability is based on all these attributes, then the cost of exercising choice is low, otherwise the cost is high.
Meanwhile, as theory implies that incentives for productivity rely on the financial outcomes related with productivity gains and losses, such repercussions are experienced at the district level since they toil through property prices, which have an effect on districts' tax revenue and districts' budgets. Thus, it is expected that productivity be influenced more by the degree of choice among districts than by the degree of choice among schools. On the contrary, sorting is expected to be impacted at least as much, if not more, by the degree of choice among schools as by the degree of choice among districts.

VI. Instruments for Measures of Tiebout Choice

The study proposes variables, particularly, streams which reflect the number of natural school district boundaries found in a metropolitan area, since the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, when school district boundaries were originally established in America, a crucial consideration was students' commute time to school. However, the rudimentary significance of natural barriers is maintained since they defined initial school district boundaries, which are the main supply side attribute that determines present boundaries. As a result, the number of school districts in a given area and at a given time of settlement was an increasing function of the number of natural barriers. 

VII. School-District Characteristics and Aggregation Issues

A. Aggregation When All the Covariates Are Exogenous
First think of the situation that would be present if measures of choice and all other covariates were exogenous. Through equation manipulation it was observed that the gain in efficiency, in relation to an aggregate regression, is because of the fact that an individual level regression creates more accurate estimates of the covariances between variables that differ at the individual or district level. Naturally, the individual level regression takes up more information for instance the fact that black children are more likely to be underprivileged.

B. Should One Worry That District-Level Means Are Endogenous to Choice?
Tiebout choice in an educational market influences the average individual qualities in each school district, where in the district mean variables are endogenous to the degree of choice in the educational market. However, the endogeneity of district mean variables to choice is irrelevant to the estimated coefficient on the magnitude of choice. By intuition, when greater choice augments the average of some attribute in one district, there is a precisely offsetting decline in the average of that attribute in other districts. Thus, although mean district qualities are endogenous to choice, the impact of choice through its effect on average attributes is automatically equal to zero.

C. Aggregation When Choice Needs to be Instrumented
Naturally, the effects of aggregation given that instruments are needed since measures of choice are likely to been endogenous. Although the insight is that the impact of choice through its effect on district average attributes is automatically equal to zero, however it would be inaccurate, to view the coefficients on district mean characteristics as if they were exogenous. Hence, district average attributes are included merely to develop the fit of the equation. Nonetheless there is no interpretation included in the result.

D. Measures of District Heterogeneity
The average level of district heterogeneity in an educational market is likely correlated with choice. Bear in mind that choice does not necessarily increase the within-district homogeneity of all attributes. Hence, the mean level of district heterogeneity in an educational market relies on the interaction between choice and the heterogeneity of the market's population. If an educational market is initially homogeneous, then a rise in choice cannot increase the homogeneity of its mean district. On the other hand, if an educational market is initially heterogeneous, then a rise in choice potentially changes the homogeneity of its mean district.

VIII. Data
  
The paper made use of several data, all coordinated geographically at the school district or metropolitan area level. The two sources of data on schools and school districts are:
1. Census of Governments (COG) (U.S. Department of Commerce, 1984), which consist of administrative data on the expenses, enrollment, and instructional employee of each district in the United States;
2. National Center of Education Statistics Common Core of Data (CCD) (U.S. Department of Education, 1995), which has administrative data on enrollment, instructional employee, and pupil demographics for each school in the United States. The only demographic information accessible at the school level is gender, race, and free lunch eligibility which is a common proxy for poverty.
The special school district tabulation of the Census of Population and Housing (SDDB) (U.S. Department of Commerce, 1983a; U.S. Department of Education, 1994b) are also utilized for data on the percentage of private school students, average demographic attributes of each district, and measures of the demographic heterogeneity of each school district. While the demographic measures at the metropolitan area level are obtained from the City and County Data Book (CCDB) (U.S. Department of Commerce, 1983b).
Lastly, to guarantee that the measure of choice is not just seeing larger metropolitan areas, measures of metropolitan-area size based on population as well as land area are included, and to make sure that the measure of choice is not just seeing regional effects, indicator variables for the nine Census regions are incorporated.
Meanwhile, the streams variables are from the U.S. Geological Survey's (USGS) 1/24,000 quadrangle maps.
The holdup in this study (as well as with other studies) is obtaining data on achievement. In order to have student data that is matched to individual school districts, the restricted-access version of the National Education Longitudinal Survey (NELS) (U.S. Department of Education, 1994a) for 8th, 10th, and 12th grade test scores was used. In addition, student achievement measures were taken from the restricted-access version of the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth (NLSY) (U.S. Department of Labor, 1998), where in the samples are older.
The school and district data have nearly no missing observations as all 6,523 regularly functioning metropolitan districts are incorporated in the regressions. Discrepancy in the accessibility of the attainment measures describes the variation in the number of observations among regressions, and most of the disparity in availability is not because of the missing observations but of the survey framework or the nature of the achievement measure.

IX. Results

The output shows that the level of choice differs broadly across metropolitan areas in the United States, not only for the reason that some metropolitan areas are bigger than others. Also there is not much variation among metropolitan areas in the degree of choice among schools. The measures of choice across districts are highly correlated. Having the significant correlation across the district-based measures, the vital disparities among them are the substantive ones, for instance, the greater information and greater likelihood for endogeneity in the enrollment-based measure. However, a metropolitan area's degree of choice among districts is not greatly correlated with its degree of choice among schools. Metropolitan areas having greater choice across districts do not essentially provide more choice among schools. The lack of correlation is crucial for two reasons, (1) peers whom a student actually has contact with relies on the school he attends, and (2) the lack of such is the key to interpreting some of the results.

A. First-Stage Results
The district-based choice index is statistically significantly related to the streams variables. Meanwhile, the streams variables have a weak statistical connection with the school-based choice index. Results indicate that if streams impact schools, it is because they affected district boundaries, not because they are otherwise important as of present.

B. The Effect of Tiebout Choice on Student Achievement
Since the interest is on the schools' productivity, it makes sense to consider first the two productivity components: student performance and school spending. Pupils belonging to households with income that is 10 percent higher have test scores that are about 0.15 standardized points greater. Females’ reading scores are 2 standardized points greater than those of males. Reading scores of Black and Hispanic pupils are 5.5 and 2.9 standardized points lower than those of white non- Hispanic pupils, respectively. Pupil whose parents have some college education but no baccalaureate degree, and pupils having parents with at least one baccalaureate degree have reading scores that are 2.3 and 5.5 standardized points greater than student whose parent has no college education, respectively. Most of the attributes of the metropolitan-area do not have statistically significant effects on achievement.
Result implies when there exists more choice among districts then the student achievement is greater. In addition, such rise in the degree of choice creates educational achievement that is 1.4 grades higher and income that is about 15 percent higher at age 32. These results are all statistically significantly different from zero.
Meanwhile, the OLS results expose the sign of the bias due to omitted variables and endogeneity. The successful districts do draw in households with students, as well as attract other districts into integration. Additionally, unobserved factors, such as dissension, that increases the demand for districts in a metropolitan area may have a negative impact on achievement. However if measures of a district heterogeneity are omitted from the equation, the estimated coefficient on choice does not vary by a statistically significant amount. Thus, the main choice impact on pupil attainment does not seem to be working through the impact of choice on the heterogeneity of districts.
The results offer little evidence of heterogeneous effects. The estimates are faintly lesser for low income families but not statistically significantly different from the estimates of the high-income families.
Another observation is that Tiebout choice does not have a statistically significant impact on the 8th-grade reading scores or the 10th-grade math scores of Black and Hispanic pupils, while the effect on non-minority pupils are statistically significant and positive. The minority-nonminority difference in the effect on 8th-grade reading scores is not statistically significant, while it is statistically significant with regards to the effect on 10th-grade math scores. However, such weak evidence of heterogeneous effects is not supported by the other measures of achievement.
Lastly, various tests failed to reject the null hypothesis that streams impact student attainment only through their effect on choice. Meanwhile the test of the exogeneity of the larger streams variable is based on the assumption that one has more a priori confidence in the exogeneity of the smaller streams variable since they are too little to have an impact on modern life. The test fails to reject the null hypothesis that the bigger streams variable is a valid instrument.
In general, an increase in Tiebout choice has a statistically significant, positive effect on measures of attainment that range from test scores to wages. Raw OLS estimates of the choice impact on pupil achievement are potentially downward biased and the stream variables seem to be valid instruments. It is likely that the effect on minority and low-income pupils is smaller than the effect on other pupils, but the evidence for such a conclusion is only suggestive. Furthermore, sorting caused by Tiebout choice may have negative effects on underprivileged students that offset some of the gains they experience from competition. On the other hand, it could also be that the choice measure is particularly erroneous for such students.

C. The Effects of Tiebout Choice on Per-Pupil Spending
Metropolitan areas with higher household incomes have greater per pupil spending, as do metropolitan areas that are more Hispanic and more racially homogeneous. Also, metropolitan areas with bigger populations have a greater private schools enrollment, as do metropolitan areas whose adults have more heterogeneous educational achievement.
Meanwhile the impact of choice on attainment seems to be significantly influenced by endogeneity and omitted variables bias, and seems there is only a slight affect on the effects of choice on per pupil expenditure.
However, an increase in choice among districts decreases per pupil spending with no decline in student attainment – this has great implications for productivity.
Interestingly, the estimated reduction in per-pupil spending is linked to a decrease in the pupil-teacher ratio or to an increase in teaching resources per student. Finally, Tiebout choice pushes districts to allot money away from other inputs and towards the reduction of pupil-ratio.

 D. The Effect of Tiebout Choice on Private-School Enrollment
The estimates suggest that a rise in the choice index leads to a fall of private school enrollment, in other words, Tiebout choice can have a significant impact on the percentage of private schools students. However, raw OLS estimation indicates that Tiebout choice has no impact on private schooling. An ineffective public school district seems to push its pupils into private schools. Since such phenomenon augments the concentration of public school pupils in some districts, it endogenously reduces the choice index based on district enrollment. The key sources of endogeneity are possibly district consolidation and the residential decisions of households with school-aged children.

E. The Effect of Tiebout Choice on Productivity
The results imply that a raise in the index of Tiebout choice among districts increases productivity. However there was no observed statistical evidence that productivity effects are different for pupils from privileged and under privileged families. Although the estimates suggests that productivity effects may be faintly higher for students from privileged families, there is still weak evidence to support that minority students encounter inferior productivity boost than other students.
Ultimately, the estimated impact of productivity for mostly state-controlled districts are constantly lower than those for mostly locally controlled districts, but none of the disparities is statistically significant. Nevertheless, the result hints that Tiebout choice has greater impact in states where districts have more financial independence.

F. Further Evidence on Tiebout Choice and Student Sorting
So far there has been little evidence that Tiebout choice has an effect on productivity via sorting. This may suggest that peer effects are small or that there are offsetting benefits and losses when pupils face heterogeneous peers.
Another observation shows that pupils are just as segregated in schools in metropolitan areas that have a small number of districts as they are in metropolitan areas that have more than a few districts. Households distribute themselves into school attendance areas within districts so that district boundaries have little impact on the racial heterogeneity faced by students.
Overall, selection among districts may only have little impact on the peers a pupil actually encounters since households distribute themselves into school-attendance areas whether or not they have much choice among districts. Thus, the impact of choice on productivity is more likely to be due to competitive pressure among districts than by sorting of students.

X. Conclusion

The first conclusion is perceived to be practical. Estimates that do not consider the school districts endogeneity are biased towards observing no effects. This is potentially because of the tendency of successful school districts to draw in households with school-aged children, thus increasing their market share and reducing the observed level of choice.
The primary finding of this study is that Tiebout choice among public school districts increases school productivity. The most striking observation is the conflicting sign of the attainment and spending results: Tiebout choice boosts productivity by simultaneously increasing achievement and decreasing spending. Also, if the potential of Tiebout choice as a policy is considered, the impacts on productivity, student performance, and per-pupil spending are significant in size.
There is also indicative evidence that Tiebout choice must have financial effects if it aims generate the productivity results described. Tiebout choice seems to have greater productivity impacts in states where school districts are more financially independent.
Meanwhile, households having Tiebout-style choice are less inclined to choose private schools and are more likely to stay in the public-school system. Although Tiebout choice among districts allows more sorting of households by district, such rise in district homogeneity have little net impact on attainment, per student spending, or productivity.
The estimated impact of Tiebout choice is not significantly affected by controlling for district-level measures of demographic heterogeneity. This is because sorting of pupils by racial and income groups is at the school level, not the district. Metropolitan areas with little Tiebout choice among districts have roughly the same level of sorting among schools as metropolitan areas with plenty of Tiebout choice among districts. Such areas having little Tiebout choice among districts could face the productivity benefits of choice with little variation in the nature of student sorting among their schools.
The results of Tiebout choice are insignificantly different for lower-income and higher-income families and for minority and nonminority families. In addition, although the sorting brought about by Tiebout choice has little general impact; it has negative results on underprivileged pupils that counterbalance some of the gains of experience from competition.



Source:
Caroline M. Hoxby, “Does Competition among Public Schools Benefit Students and Taxpayers?” The American Economic Review, Vol. 90, No. 5, (December 2000), pp. 1209-1238.

0 comments:

Post a Comment